Trade between and
among people is beautiful. What one does not need because he has surplus
production, he can sell it and get those things he does not have but he needs,
via purchase or via the old system of barter.
Countries and economies that trade more are more
advanced, more developed compared to countries that are less friendly to more
international trade.
That is why free trade has become a known policy and
advocacy in many countries for centuries now. Import tariff rates have been
declining significantly, down to zero for some economies like Hong Kong and
Singapore.
But protectionist interests have invented many types of
non-tariff barriers (NTBs) or non-tariff measures and these limit or restrict
trade.
Among the less-visible type of NTBs are the various
business bureaucracies and regulations. For instance, while it is possible to
require only three documents to allow exporters and importers to ship or
receive their products, other Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN)
countries require six to 10 documents.
Here is one result of the World Bank’s Doing Business
2015 Report, section on International Trade. There were 189 countries covered
in that report. Global ranks of ASEAN countries are given.
It would take around three weeks for an exporter to
finally move his containers out of Cambodia, Laos, Myanmar, and Vietnam, too
long compared to less than one week in Singapore and around two weeks for
exporters in Malaysia and Thailand.
It is really possible to cut the time to export to just
11 days or less, as shown by Singapore and Malaysia plus the seven countries
above. The eight other governments in the ASEAN need not hold back the exports
of their entrepreneurs for two weeks or more.
A similar measurement of bureaucracies and taxes as new
variety of NTBs is covered by Fraser Institute’s Economic Freedom of the World
(EFW) annual reports. The EFW is composed of five areas, including the freedom
to trade internationally. This area is composed of four sub-areas: (A) Tariffs,
(B) Regulatory trade barriers, (C) Black market exchange rates, and (D)
Controls of movement of capital and people.
The EFW employs a scoring system of zero to 10, where
zero is totally unfree and 10 means there is full economic freedom. Thus, high
revenues from trade taxes, high tariff, wide variations and deviation of tariff
rates mean low score. And more regulatory barriers, more NTBs also mean low
score, low degrees of economic freedom for entrepreneurs.
For this piece, sub-areas A and B are shown. Laos was not
included in the EFW report. Hong Kong is added here as “benchmark” for being
the freest economy in the world.
The above numbers show that ASEAN countries generally
have low tariff rates, with scores of eight to almost 10 (Singapore and
Brunei). This is a reflection of the accelerated trade liberalization policy in
the region.
But there are problems too, like having wide variations
and high standard deviations in tariff rates. Singapore, Malaysia, Thailand,
and Vietnam have scores below six.
The member-governments of the ASEAN need to be reminded
from time to time that the main purpose of trade liberalization is to empower
the consumers and producers of their own countries with more choices. NTBs and
complicated bureaucracies defeat or undermine that goal.
Free trade means free individuals, free enterprises.
Restrictions to trade is restricting individual and economic freedom, the
freedom to choose and compete, where and from whom to buy and to whom to sell.
Some consumers though can lose from free trade and
unilateral liberalization if the goods they regularly consume are being
exported because prices can go higher. But this loss is temporary because more
goods, more choices from abroad will become available in the domestic market.
Multilateral trade negotiations for free trade are too
unwieldy and costly, time-consuming and bureaucratic. Regional and bilateral
free trade agreements (FTAs) are faster in producing agreements and results but
they are selective and become an excuse for protectionism against countries
where no FTAs are signed yet.
Unilateral trade liberalization, no need for or minimum
of negotiations, just open the borders at zero tariff and minimal
bureaucracies, is pro-development. There is little or no justification to
restrict trade as it is a voluntary exchange between two or more entities --
individuals, companies, and institutions.
People and companies, not nations and governments, trade
with each other. Governments therefore should reduce restrictions on people and
goods mobility.
In particular: (a) reduce tariff and non-tariff barriers
like quantitative restrictions and customs bureaucracies, and (b) simplify visa
requirements and issuance, reduce the cost of migration.
The main function of government in trade is to help
enforce contracts and promulgate the rule of law. And the only justifiable
considerations for governments to regulate trade are those involving public
health and safety. Like bringing in or exporting weapons, ammunitions,
dangerous substances, counterfeit or substandard medicines, virus-infected
animals, etc.
All other goods should be allowed entry with the minimum
or zero restrictions and taxation. This will significantly bring down prices
and benefit consumers, especially the poor.
Two groups of people dislike unilateral trade
liberalization: (a) the protected local businesses and cronies, political
interest groups like militant trade unions and farmer organizations, and (b)
trade negotiators and consultants who regularly fly and have endless meetings
in some beautiful and expensive hotels and cities abroad.
Smuggling can be beneficial to consumers through lower
prices compared to protectionist prices. But this expands corruption in
government. To remove the opportunities for corruption and rent-seeking and at
the same time give consumers and local producers the freedom to get cheaper
goods and services, protectionism should be abandoned and unilateral
liberalization should be pursued.
Other institutional constraints like protectionist constitutions
that explicitly protect domestic business interests and limit foreign
competition should be amended to allow or encourage more foreign investments
and trade.
Bienvenido S. Oplas, Jr. heads a free-market think tank,
Minimal Government Thinkers, Inc., and is a fellow of the South East Asia
Network for Development (SEANET).
-----------
See also:
BWorld 14, OFWs, MERS-CoV and the DFA, August 08, 2015
BWorld 15, The PH electricity market, August 15, 2015
BWorld 16, Growth, capitalism and inequality, August 22, 2015
BWorld 17, More on the Philippine electricity market, August 30, 2015
Free Trade 52, More on the Gravity model, September 08, 2015
No comments:
Post a Comment