Free trade is part of human nature. People may oppose it philosophically but consciously or unconsciously, they are engaged in it. Even militant protectionism crusaders are still humans, they need to eat, and they want free choice where to eat. Do not go to restaurants that are too expensive for their budget, never go back to a resto which may be cheap but the service is too annoying. They want to be served well given their budget, or they may endure bad service in exchange for really cheap food. That is the beauty of voluntary exchange, no one is forced and coerced to give his/her money to people who do not provide their specific needs. That is the beauty of free trade.
Some countries and economies have taken the
unilateral trade liberalization route -- Hong Kong, Singapore, Dubai, Chile, among others. And have good results. Chart below shows that as of 2001, average tariff in S. America was around 12 percent vs around 4 percent in East Asia, zero already in Singapore. East Asians are more receptive to unilateral trade liberalization than their counterparts in S. America or Africa.
Applied Most Favoured Nation (MFN) Tariff Liberalization in Latin America
and East Asia.
When it comes to agricultural products though, economies in general are more protectionist even if they may be relatively free traders in non-agri products. Stark cases are Korea, Turkey, Egypt and Thailand.
The exceptions to this agricultural protectionism are the unilateral Asian free traders HK and Singapore, and some countries in S. America, Argentina and Brazil. Data also from R.
Baldwin.
In this working paper at the WB, Nogues argued that "Developing countries would gain far more from unilateral than multilateral trade liberalization negotiations over many years."
(Julio Nogues, 1989. "The Choice Between Unilateral and Multilateral Trade Liberalization Strategies", 24 pages), http://wwwwds.worldbank.org/.../Rendered/PDF/multi0page.pdf
Chile experience is fantastic, from 220 percent tariff in 1973 to only 11 percent in 1991 (only 18 years after.)
Source: Sebastian Edwards and Daniel
Lederman, 1998. "The Political Economy of Unilateral Trade Liberalization: The
Case of Chile", NBER working paper, http://www.nber.org/papers/w6510.pdf
A Cato paper, A Cautionary Tale on Negotiated vs. Unilateral TradeLiberalization (November 21, 2012), author Sallie James wrote,
But since the 1950s...trade theory has pretty-much consistently shown a hierarchy of mechanisms for increasing commerce across borders: unilateral trade liberalization is best, followed by multilateral trade liberalization (although the current WTO round of trade negotiations is dead), and then regional or bilateral agreements.
Ordinary consumers and independent researchers, them who are not corrupted by government and foreign aid money and consulting, should push the logic of unilateral trade liberalization. Ordinary consumers benefit from more choices, more options, where to buy and whom to sell.
------------
See also:
Free Trade 35: EU-FNF Forum on 'FDI Engine for Job Growth', May 15, 2014
Free Trade 36: Taxation, Regulations, Trade and Rule of Law in ASEAN, August 05, 2014
Free Trade 37: Multiple Concerns and Regulations in the ASEAN, September 11, 2014
Free Trade 38: Liberalize Rice Imports and Demonopolize NFA, September 28, 2014
No comments:
Post a Comment