The key to cheaper prices and/or good services is more
competition among more players, more voluntary exchange, and not more price
coercion by regulators. If buyers do not like the price of seller A, they can
opt out and go to sellers B, C, and so on. Seller A is then pressured to lower
his price to compete with other sellers.
The key to expensive prices and/or lousy services is more
government regulation and curtailing voluntary exchange. Buyers are forced to
buy from expensive sellers and opting out is not allowed. This happens in
government-created monopolies like tricycle routes, electric cooperatives, or
government-favored sectors like producers of new renewables like solar and wind
power.
The Department of Energy (DoE) along with the United
States Agency for International Development (USAID) conducted a public
consultation last June 16 at Shangri-La at the Fort, Bonifacio Global City
about the proposed or draft Department Circular (DC) on the Renewable Portfolio
Standard (RPS). The activity was hurriedly organized and was not posted on the
DoE’s Web site.
But I heard about it from a friend and then I wrote to
DoE’s Mario Marasigan and asked if I could attend it and he said yes. Thank you
Sir Mario.
Here is a quick backgrounder of the subject.
1. Under the Renewable Energy (RE) Act of 2008 (RA 9513),
RPS is defined as a “policy that requires electricity suppliers to source an
agreed portion of their energy supply from eligible RE resources.”
2. Under the Implementing Rules and Regulations (IRR),
Section 4, RPS, “...Annual minimum incremental percentage of electricity sold
by each RPS-mandated electricity industry participant which is required to be
sourced from eligible RE Resources and which shall, in no case, be less than
one percent (1%) of its annual energy demand over the next ten (10) years.”
3. Under the draft DC discussed by the DoE last June 16,
Section 8. “The minimum annual increment in the RPS level shall be initially
set at 2.15% to be applied to the actual total supply portfolio of the Mandated
Participant in each grid for the previous year.”
4. Under the Annex table, RPS Calculation, also prepared
by the DoE that day, the cumulative RE capacity that will be needed from 2016
to 2030 is a glaring 30,862 MW (30.86 GW) or an average of 2.06 GW/year
increase for RE alone (see Table 1).
During the open forum, I asked about many consumers’
concern about expensive electricity. What would be the implication in pricing
of the proposed RPS, if they impose a 1.5% annual marginal increment (AMI)? How
about at 1.75% or at 2.15% (their proposed rate)? And if they target 30%
renewables in the energy mix by 2030, or 32% or 35% (their proposed target),
what would be the impact on electricity prices?
The feed in tariff (FIT) without RPS was already four
centavos per kilowatt-hour (kWh) last year, 12 centavos per kWh this year, so
with FIT + RPS next year, will it become 20 centavos? 25 centavos?
DoE officials answered that no study on price
implications has been worked out yet and that it can come out later as the
current focus is the mechanisms on how RPS will be implemented, including
penalties for violators or non-implementers of RPS.
So it is a weird circular because both the DoE and the
National Renewable Energy Board (NREB), the multi-stakeholder body that
recommends policy options for the DoE, are pushing for a policy where they
admittedly do not have a clear idea on the cost of implementation to energy
consumers.
One thing that can be favorable for RPS though is that
distribution utilities (DUs) will have more options from among renewable
technologies -- biomass, waste to energy, geothermal, run of river hydro,
impounded hydro, wind, solar, ocean, hybrid systems, others -- and choose those
that are least cost.
The above RPS and RE targets by 2030 are not practical
and not viable because the Philippines is still way below many of its neighbors
in power generation and we need to grow fast to sustain the economic momentum
of recent years and create more businesses, more jobs to more people.
People who push for higher renewables in the national
energy mix want to push out coal power as much or as soon as possible. This is
a day-dream and illusionary goal because of the big role that coal power
contributes to many industrialized and emerging Asian economies. From 2000 to
2015, Indonesia, Malaysia and Vietnam ramped up their coal power capacity from
375% to 609%. The Philippines’ 11.4 gigawatt (GW) coal capacity in 2015 was
only one-half that of Vietnam’s 22 GW, only one-third that of Taiwan’s and
nearly one-eighth of South Korea’s.
For Table 2, definition of the following terms:
a. 1 terawatt (TW) = 1,000 gigawatt (GW) = 1,000,000
megawatt (MW)
b. MTOE = Million tons of oil equivalent
c. 1 MTOE = produces about 4.4 terawatt-hour (TWh) of
electricity in a modern power station.
The share of wind and solar in total electricity
production in the Philippines is small, only about 0.8% of the total in 2015,
despite their installed power share of around 2.5%-3% of total installed
capacity. The explanation for this is the low capacity factor of these new
renewables.
Some people insist that there is already “grid parity” by
the new renewables with coal and natural gas, that “solar is cheaper than coal”
now. If this is true, then why are they asking for another round of energy
coercion through high RPS, on top of existing coercions on FIT (guaranteed
price for 20 years) + priority dispatch to the grid + fiscal incentives?
A developing country like the Philippines should be given
more leeway in building up cheaper and stable energy sources.
Energy poverty and expensive electricity result in lack
of jobs because energy-intensive industries and companies would avoid the
Philippines and go to energy-stable and competitively-priced economies like
Malaysia, Indonesia, Vietnam and Thailand.
The DoE should either implement the minimum 1% of AMI in
RPS, or further delay RPS implementation until the price implications are
studied and the consumers are not further burdened with higher prices and
unstable electricity supply.
Bienvenido S. Oplas, Jr. is a Fellow of SEANET and
Stratbase-ADRi, and heads a free market think tank, Minimal Government
Thinkers.
--------------
See also:
BWorld 51, WESM as market-oriented, PEMC as bureaucracy-oriented, March 25, 2016
BWorld 55, FIT-All, renewables and elections 2016, April 23, 2016
BWorld 58, INDCs and PH energy realities, May 14, 2016
BWorld 64, The WTO and trade agreements, June 17, 2016 BWorld 65, PH exports growth from 1960-2014, June 22, 2016
No comments:
Post a Comment